Introduction.
Humanity’s rate of use of fossil fuels for energy has grown to high
levels in recent decades, and is projected to continue increasing for the
indefinite future. As a result, the
annual rate of emission of carbon dioxide (CO2), the main greenhouse
gas, as well as other greenhouse gases such as methane, has likewise been
increasing. Most CO2, once it
enters the atmosphere, remains there indefinitely for a century or longer, for
there is no naturally occurring mechanism that removes it.
Climate scientists
hold greenhouse gases responsible for the recent long-term increase in the
world-wide average temperature. In turn,
the warmer planet harbors an increased potential for more, and more intense,
extreme weather and climate events such as rainfall and resulting floods, heat
waves and resulting droughts, and wildfires.
These events have catastrophic effects on human populations, and inflict
serious economic harms.
These
considerations lead climate scientists and economists to develop mitigating
policies intended to slow the growth in the rate of emissions. This would have the effect of lowering the
rate of increase in the CO2 content of the atmosphere. It must be noted that, because CO2
remains resident in the atmosphere for a century or longer, its atmospheric
concentration cannot be reduced within reasonable time frames; even if
emissions ceased entirely, the result would be merely to stabilize the CO2
concentration at the new, higher level.
One policy intended to abate the rate of emission of CO2 is
to impose an economic hurdle to use of fossil fuels. This post describes recent opinion articles
proposing use of a carbon tax or a gas tax to accomplish this.
Two Economics
Commentators have recently come
out in support of a carbon tax. Robert
Frank, professor of economics at Cornell, commenting in the New York Times, advocates a carbon tax for the following reasons. First, he summarized some of the adverse
weather events in the U. S. mentioned above in the Introduction,
emphasizing that climate scientists today believe that man-made greenhouse
gases building up in the atmosphere contribute to the causes of these events. Dr. Frank cites a global climate model study
by Sokolov and coworkers that concludes that the global average temperature in 2045 has a median
probability of increasing by 1.85ºC (3.3ºF), and by 5.1ºC (9.2ºF) by 2095,
beyond the present level, which has itself already increased about 0.7ºC
(1.3ºF) above the temperature that prevailed before humans began burning fossil
fuels. These predictions, based on Sokolov’s
current more comprehensive model, are higher than earlier ones by his group and
by others.
Dr. Frank then suggests
gradually imposing a carbon tax in the U. S., citing an earlier recommendation
by the U. N. Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change for a tax of
US$80/metric ton (1.1 U. S. tons) of emitted carbon, which works out to about
70 US cents per U. S. gallon of gasoline.
However, in view of the more dire temperature rise situation currently
foreseen he also suggests a tax that could be as high as US$300/metric ton,
translating to a rise in the price of gasoline of about US$3.00/U. S.
gallon. Many countries around the world
already have taxes on fuel about this high, and, he notes, nations have adapted
by developing more efficient cars.
Dr. Frank cites two
beneficial economic effects of a carbon tax.
First, it would contribute to reducing the U. S. fiscal deficit, which is highly
desirable. In addition, phasing in the
tax gradually only after the present economic distress in the U. S. had passed would provide a timed incentive
to make energy use in all its aspects more efficient even before the tax took
effect, thus contributing overall to a reduced rate of emitting greenhouse
gases. The U. S. could contribute to a worldwide increase in
energy efficiency by imposing carbon-based tariffs on imports. This, for example, would provide incentives
for foreign emitters of large amounts of greenhouse gases to develop
efficiencies in their own lands.
Dr. Frank concludes
“If the recent meteorological chaos drives home the threat of climate change
and prompts action, it may ultimately be a blessing in disguise.”
Eduardo Porter, an
economics columnist with the New York Times supports a more limited carbon tax in the form of a
gas tax. Mr. Porter noted that President
Obama’s administration has ruled that motor vehicle fleet average gas
efficiency has to reach 54.5 miles per U. S. gallon by 2025, almost doubling the present
efficiency. (In a previous action his
administration had set a standard of 36.6 miles per U. S. gallon by 2017.) The administration foresees that by 2025
these standards should result in a reduction of fuel use by 12 billion gallons,
with a concomitant lowering of greenhouse gas emissions when burned.
But Mr. Porter has
several concerns with the use of vehicle efficiency standards to lower use of
fossil fuels for transportation. First,
he states that the engineering, production and societal costs to attain such
efficiency may be excessive, representing an ineffective use of productive
resources. This is so even accounting
for the reduction in harms inflicted by lowered incidence of weather extremes,
and better health such as lower incidence of asthma, according to
economists. Second, he warns that more
efficient vehicles may have the “perverse incentive” of inducing drivers to
travel more, not less, because the expense per distance traveled will be lower. In other words, vehicle efficiency standards
do not change behavior toward reducing use of fossil fuels. Further, they only take effect as people move
from older, less efficient cars to newer, efficient ones, a process that
stretches out over the decade or more needed for the fleet standard to be put
in place.
Instead, Mr. Porter
favors a gas tax. First, a gas tax directly
affects drivers’ behavior right away, even with their existing vehicles. They would travel less, and when they decide
to buy new cars, they would opt for more efficient ones which in turn provides
the incentive to manufacturers to optimize efficiency. This effect has already been observed when
gas prices rose in the past for brief episodes.
Second, any inequity in imposing a gas tax can be reversed by offering
tax credits at income tax time, say, to people with lower incomes; behavior at
the pump is affected by the price tag staring drivers in the face rather than
by the distant, subconscious, expectation of a return of the tax at a later
time. Third, the gas tax spurs car
makers to make the most efficient vehicles they think drivers would buy in
response to the newly imposed gas tax.
Mr. Porter cites a currently circulating analysis by Prof. Christopher
Knittel, an energy economist at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology, that
found that if a gas tax had been imposed in the 1980’s, after the Arab oil
embargo, gas mileage could have improved by 60% by now. Instead, car makers have emphasized
increasing size, weight and power.
Tom Friedman, a
foreign affairs columnist for the New York Times, has repeatedly called for a
tax on carbon as the most direct way to lower consumption of fossil fuels, in
order to minimize the growth of greenhouse gases in the atmosphere and to
reduce U.
S.
importation of petroleum from abroad.
Others at the New York Times espousing a carbon tax, both conservatives and liberals, are David Brooks, Nicholas Kristof and Bob
Herbert.
In 2011, Profs.
Daniel Esty (Commissioner of Energy and Environmental Protection for the state
of Connecticut ) and Michael Porter published an op-ed article in the New York Times espousing a carbon tax.
Analysis
Cap-and-Trade
Mechanisms to Lower
CO2
Emissions. Two principal
economic mechanisms have been devised to lower the rate of emissions of
greenhouse gases, including CO2.
One is the cap-and-trade mechanism.
In this regime the government jurisdiction (region, nation or state)
administratively establishes how many emission allowances, usually worth the
right to emit 1 ton of CO2, for example, that each fixed point
source of emissions (e.g., a power plant) is allowed. These are granted or sold to the source. Accordingly, cap-and-trade requires initially
establishing the emissions rate for each source, which relies on reporting from
the sources without bias. The total of
all allowances constitutes the “cap”.
Allowances have value, because a source that succeeds in reducing its
emission rate can “trade” them on an open market to other sources whose
emission rate exceeds their allowances.
Cap-and-trade is intended to lower overall emission rates with time, as
the administering government lowers the cap each year; this would result in
increasing the price of each
allowance. The result is to lower
emissions, while reflecting the price of the allowances by an increased cost for
generating power or using energy, which is passed on to consumers.
Thus cap-and-trade
uses market forces to, on the one hand, induce conservation behavior by
consumers, and on the other hand, to induce efficiencies in generation of
energy. A further complication, though,
is the right usually built in to cap-and-trade regimes to “offset” excess
demand for allowances by “importing” allowances from outside the territory of
the regime; these also must be monitored effectively by those administering the
regime.
Cap-and-trade, it
can be seen carries several difficulties and inefficiencies. Its administration is very complex: there is
the need to allot allowances and lower them each year; market mechanisms must
be established; and offsets must be monitored.
Additionally, the market for allowances establishes third-party traders
having no interest in global warming, but only in trading an object (allowances)
for profit among themselves, potentially leading to market abuses and
speculation.
The European Union
established a cap-and-trade in the last decade, but it was initially judged a failure because it wound up
issuing more allowances than necessary, leading to a collapse of the
market. On the other hand, the American
regimes in California , and in the Northeast Regional Greenhouse
Gas Initiative, are operating cap-and-trade regimes at various stages of
progress.
A Carbon Tax or
a Gas Tax. The second principal mechanism for lowering
emission rates is imposition of a tax on all forms CO2 emissions,
frequently including other greenhouse gases, or a more limited tax on gasoline
only. A carbon tax impacts all sources
of energy and economic activity that depend on fossil fuels. A gasoline tax is more restricted to limiting
use of fossil fuels for personal and commercial transportation.
Administratively a
carbon tax is far simpler than setting up a cap-and-trade regime. It too is based on economic behavior,
affecting the demand side of the market, as opposed to the supply side impacted
by cap-and-trade. Typically a carbon tax
is imposed gradually, beginning at a low level and increasing annually to an
economically meaningful level. A
political “sweetener” for a carbon tax could be a rebate to needy taxpayers to
compensate for the increased year-long expense arising from the tax, as noted
above.
This writer
believes that a carbon tax is preferable over a cap-and-trade regime for its
simplicity, efficiency and effectiveness.
Mr. Porter’s
article above cites U. S. government studies on the overall “social
cost of carbon”, per ton of CO2 emitted. This arises from harms due to extreme weather
and climate events, and adverse effects on health and nutrition from global
warming. These calculations are subject
to great uncertainties, but economists place the cost at between US$5 to 68,
and increasing even more as time passes.
It thus behooves all societies, including our own, to take active
measures to lower emissions, striving to attain zero emissions as soon as
possible in order to minimize the harms from extreme events.
Gas taxes are very
effective in affecting drivers’ travel habits.
The graphic below
Sources: New York Times presenting data from the U. S. Department of Energy and the World Bank; http://www.nytimes.com/interactive/2012/09/11/business/Fuel-Taxes-and-Consumption.html?ref=business
Conclusion.
Frank and Porter have proposed imposing a carbon tax or a gasoline tax
to abate further increases in the rate of emission of greenhouse gases. A carbon tax is judged to be more
straightforward, efficient and effective than implementing a cap-and-trade
regime for reducing emissions. No
government bureaucracies need to be created, and the simplest of motives
driving economic activity by individuals have an immediate effect on behavior. Where deemed necessary, tax rebates could be
devised to ease the tax burden on people with low incomes. A carbon tax additionally would have positive
effects on American society, for it would contribute to resolving our severe
fiscal problems. Policymakers should
give serious consideration to this mechanism for abating greenhouse gas
emissions.
© 2012 Henry Auer
No comments:
Post a Comment